A history of the Corporation

There have always been large organizations that have done the kinds of things corporations do, but for most of human history, large organizations were run by religious hierarchies or governments rather than for-profit businesses. For-profit businesses were always small which is nowadays defined as less than 500 employees, and businesses were much smaller than that and they were usually run by families until the rise of the corporation and other large businesses (trusts and partnerships) that were part of the advent of capitalism.  One reason businesses were small was that there weren’t any private-sector business activities that required huge scale.  Only governments and churches undertook activities that required more than about a hundred workers.  Some “private” businesses did grow bigger than 100 workers, but they were primarily government contractors that were engaged in public works such as the publicani of the Roman Republic. 

The publicani said to be the earliest precursor of the corporation because they were large organizations with diffuse ownership, but there are some crucial differences such as the fact that membership in the publicani was more like club membership and shares were not bought and sold on a free market. Plus, the publicani solely served the government rather than profiting from entrepreneurial activities.  They were purely agents of the state unlike most modern corporations whose business models are directed by market incentives. 

William N. Goetzmann and K. Geert Rouwenhorst argue that there are three distinguishing features of a modern corporation but publicani only have the first two:

First, [a corporation’s] existence is not affected by the departure of individual members. This stability enhances its ability to participate in economic transactions.

This isn’t really unique to corporations. Most big organizations share this feature: Churches, cities, and governments, and modern society increasingly categorizes all big organizations as corporations, but this essay is defining a corporation as a for-profit business as opposed to non-profit and governmental corporations. 

As corporations get more complex, they require more separation of ownership from control.   But it is a remarkable fact that only a very small percent of private businesses in all of history have been able to survive the death or departure of an owner partly because most businesses have always been sole proprietorships (72% of US businesses today) or partnerships (10% of US businesses today) which are designed to be embodied in the owner unlike corporations.  The word corporation literally means “body” partly because a corporation is a separate legal person from those who work in it which is the second characteristic:

Second, designated members of the company can represent it, in other words, they can enter contracts without assuming rights or duties themselves. Instead, the company becomes the bearer of all obligations.

This is the idea of a corporation having legal personhood so that it can make contracts and bear responsibility for problems rather than transferring liabilities on workers or owners. Legally, only a person can be sued which has never been a problem for a businesses that is either a sole proprietorship or partnership, but it is more complicated for corporations.  Limited liability for corporate owners is a surprisingly modern phenomenon (see below), but large organizations inherently diffuse responsibility and hence liability.  Publicani members technically had legal liability for the organization under Roman law, but there was a huge loophole. A publicani’s owners could entrust a slave to manage the publicani and then the owners could argue that they should not be held responsible for what the slave did, and then the slave could bear all the liability. Furthermore, another longstanding method for shielding corporate investors from liability is by structuring shares as debts rather than shares of ownership because debts always have limited liability.  Lenders can only lose as much as their past contributions, just like modern corporate shareholders. 

Corporations necessarily need to empower their CEO or managers to take on liabilities (and all contracts involve some sort of liability), but the practice of completely insulating shareholders from all liability was illegal until the middle of the 19th century.

After shareholders were freed from the last vestiges of legal responsibility for owning firms that committed crimes, and this caused investors to feel free to diversify ownership across a multitude of companies without fear of losing more than their initial investment. This freedom magnified the separation of ownership from control:

Imagine a person who owns a horse: “If the horse lives, he must feed it. If the horse dies, he must bury it. No such responsibility attaches to a share of stock. The owner is practically powerless through his own efforts to affect the underlying property.” This is what happened at US Steel. At its founding in 1901, it was but the lengthened shadow of two men, Andrew Carnegie and J.P. Morgan. By 1932, its shareholders numbered almost 175,000, with each individual “owner” controlling nothing. Many companies in the United States followed this pattern …and …became bigger and more complex. Seeking outside investment, they took on thousands of stockholders, and ownership and management began to go their separate ways.

The other unique feature of modern corporations that was required to allow owners to diversify was the advent of stock markets where shares were easily bought and sold just like the debt markets which had already existed for centuries. The first stock exchange was in Amsterdam where the shares of the first modern corporation were traded. The first corporation in the modern sense of the word was the Dutch East India Corporation (VOC) because it was the first publicly traded corporation with all the core features of modern corporations.  This leads to the third feature of a corporation:

Third, …ownership is fungible and shareholders can react to changes in a firm’s prospects …by buying or selling shares. The separation of ownership and management makes it easier to attract human and financial capital.

This is a huge difference between modern corporations and the Roman publicani. The kind of publicani shares that gave ownership control were more like a kind of club membership and were not bought and sold on secondary markets.  Although some modern authors claim that shares were sometimes bought and sold, there is no primary evidence. For example, there was no stock exchange of any sort in the Roman world and it isn’t even clear if the ‘shares’ of the publicani were ownership stakes or if they were just variable-interest-rate loans. The latter is more likely because loans were a common feature of business across the ancient world and the first tradeable governement bonds were issued by Genoa in 1214 and the practice spread across northern Italy despite the Catholic Church’s ban on charging interest.  . 

Nick Szabo says the Italian city-states of northern Italy redeveloped something like the publicani during the renaissance and again their main purpose was tax farming:

The medieval organizations that most resembled later joint-stock corporations were the Genovese maone. … The Italian cities often sold off their tax receivables to wealthy merchants at a discount as a way to borrow funds. …The debts were divided into equal shares called loca or partes. Legally, these shares were personal property (chattels) and could be freely traded.

Technically, no organization was created when the city sold its tax receivables to merchants. However, to effectively collect the taxes, the holders of loca formed an organization called a maona or societas comperarum. This organization would then subcontract to tax farmers to collect the taxes. By the fourteenth century, Genovese maone also engaged in military conquest and colonization… Normally, maone were temporary, but some of them ended up lasting for a long time. In 1346 the Maona di Chio e di Focea … was formed. This organization’s members obtained from Genoa the exclusive right to collect taxes from Chios (an Aegean island) and Phocaea (a port on the Anatolian coast). But first the company would have to conquer them! Although technically a temporary organization, it lasted until 1566.

Rather than going to buy receivables from Genoa, subscriptions to the di Chio e di Focea’s loca shares (still legally debt, but to be paid out in dividends as taxes and trading revenues were collected) went to fund 29 galleys to conquer Chios and Phocaea. The Genovese Republic, for a fee, granted the organization exclusive rights to collect taxes from the conquered territories as well as special trading privileges. The conquests, taxes, and trading were at least partially successful, and by the 16th century more than 600 persons owned loca of the maona.

A huge difference between how the publicani and maone operated modern corporations is the fact that the publicani were not businesses that served the private sector at all. They were solely government leaseholders or contractors. They were most famous for managing tax collection and in many ways they functioned more like a form of government bureaucracy than today’s private corporations. It was a competitive form of bureaucracy, but it served as an arm of government, not a creature of markets.  After the Roman Republic turned into the Roman Empire, the government phased out publicani contracts and “without the support of the government, the societas publicanorum drifted into obscurity.”

Although the publicani disappeared, Romans had other forms of corporations that were non-profit and served religious and public functions which survived the fall of the Roman Empire such as cities, hospitals, guilds, monastic orders, and the Catholic Church itself.

Glyn Holton argues that modern corporations evolved out of medieval guilds:

This changed around 1600, when new business forms emerged to challenge the might of Spain and Portugal… Portugal had discovered the East Indies as the source of spices, and Spain was plundering the Americas for gold and silver. The Vatican legitimized this arrangement, ruling that lands discovered in the Eastern Hemisphere belonged to Portugal while lands discovered in the Western Hemisphere belonged to Spain. Holland and England flaunted the Vatican’s law. Not only did they practice a different religion, but they adopted different methods. While the Spanish and Portuguese sovereigns shouldered the expenses and risks of overseas ventures, English and Dutch traders formed private corporations to challenge them.

These trading corporations had their roots in guilds. During the 14th and 15th centuries, guilds were chartered primarily to enforce a monopoly in certain businesses or geographic regions. In exchange for a grant of monopoly, a guild would make ongoing fee payments to its chartering [government]. Members of a guild might compete with one another, but outsiders were excluded.

Traders also formed guilds. Their purpose was to secure from the government a grant of monopoly over trade with specific geographic regions. In England, such guilds were called regulated companies. They were often referred to by names reflecting their monopolies—the India Company, African Company, Russia Company, Turkey Company, etc.

…Regulated companies that sponsored equity-financed voyages came to be called joint-stock companies. Two early joint stock companies were Holland’s and England’s respective East India Companies, which were chartered to challenge Portugal’s dominance of the spice islands. Initially, neither company had permanent equity. Each voyage would have its own equity subscription. This proved impractical, and soon capital from one voyage was being rolled over to finance subsequent voyages. In this way, the companies evolved to become much like today’s business corporations. They had separate managers and investors.

A modern corporation could not arise until the VOC in the 1600s for the same reason that other forms of mass democracy could not arise until mass media technologies were invented.

The innovation that allowed corporations to dramatically expand ownership was the printing press.  A corporation is a form of mass democracy and just as democratic participation in government is limited in scope by communication technologies, so is democratic participation in investing and managing a private company.  Early corporations first arose in the most democratic states of their day perhaps because the social technology of democracy was already in use the public sphere and was easier to copy to private business or vice versa. 

A corporation requires cheap communication technologies to convince a wide array of investors that their money will not be squandered and in turn to give shareholders a say in how the company is run by giving them the power to elect representatives to the corporation’s board of directors.  Once printing became cheap enough to spread this kind of information, corporations became a viable way of bringing together not just a relatively insular group of acquaintances, but investors who have mostly never met in their lives.

The main difficulty of a corporation is achieving the shareholders’ trust in the management and that requires regular communication.  Mass communication allows trust to spread much more widely, but trust also requires accountability and that requires accounting. 

Luca de Pacioli published the first book on accounting in 1494.  His book disseminated a double-entry bookkeeping standard that across the world whose fundamentals are basically unchanged after more than 500 years.  Without that kind of accounting standard, modern corporations and capitalism would have been impossible. 

Although today it seems inevitable that corporations would eventually rule the world, corporations were often unpopular because of numerous corporate scandals and government bailouts. Although we remember the few big successes like the East India Company and the Hudson Bay Company, most corporations were usually unpopular partly because most of them were corrupt and/or went bankrupt despite various advantages such as a government-enforced monopoly. For example, Adam Smith (1776) denounced corporations in The Wealth of Nations because he thought corporate governance was so inherently flawed, it could never achieve anything beyond what you might see in a Dilbert cartoon.

…The directors of [joint stock companies] being the managers rather of other people’s money than of their own, it cannot well be expected, that they should watch over it with the same anxious vigilance with which the partners of a private copartnery frequently watch over their own … Negligence and profusion, therefore, must always prevail, more or less, in the management of the affairs of such a company. It is upon this account, that joint stock companies for foreign trade have seldom been able to maintain the competition against private adventurers. They have, accordingly, very seldom succeeded without a [monopoly]…

Adam Smith then goes on and on with examples of the foibles and crimes of his contemporary corporations that make episodes of The Office look like a well-run bureaucracy. In 1720, The British Parliament passed the Bubble Act which restricted the formation of corporations for over a century without permission from Parliament or a Royal Charter. But after the industrial revolution began transforming Britain, the government started making it easier to form corporations again. Glyn Holton again:

Incorporation by Registration

A recurring theme in the history of corporations is that they should exist to serve some public purpose, and they are granted certain privileges to facilitate this. The state would charter corporations that it deemed worthy. At first, the most important privilege was a grant of some monopoly—say a monopoly over trade with some region or an exclusive right to build a certain canal. Over time, transferability of shares and limited liability became more important. These gave corporations an enormous advantage in raising capital over sole proprietorships and partnerships. Investors with modest holdings and limited liability were comfortable letting specialists run their corporations, so the separation of investors and management became one of the great strengths—and great weaknesses—of limited liability joint-stock corporations.

The building of highways, canals and railroads was a quintessential public need, and numerous corporations were chartered for these purposes. For other businesses, the state’s monopoly on granting corporate status proved onerous. When entrepreneurs tried to form a new corporation, competitors could oppose their petition for incorporation. Inevitably, the process was marked by political intrigue. When incorporation was denied, entrepreneurs had meager options. They might buy a failing corporation as a shell and then raise capital for a business unrelated to that corporation’s original monopoly. This practice was called charter abuse. With the supply of failing corporations limited, a more common solution was to simply issue stock in unincorporated companies. This legally perilous practice became widespread in England during the late 1700s… In the early 1800s, competitors started challenging their legality in court.

The …courts and governments found themselves making increasingly arbitrary decisions about which businesses to favor. Something had to be done. The solution was a new concept: incorporation by registration. In various countries, legislation was passed [in 1844] allowing entrepreneurs to incorporate any firm they liked by simply filing paperwork. No longer would corporations be privileged associations granted monopolies by the state to pursue some public purpose. They had become a standard business form—along with sole proprietorships and partnerships—that was available to all.

This was a big difference between the corporations of the past which were supposed to advance some aims of the government versus the corporations of the present which are solely intended to serve their (disproportionately wealthy) owners.  Most corporations originally had a charter of limited duration,  generally 10 to 40 years, and had to be liquidated upon expiration if a new charter was not granted.  This was a reasonable expectation at the time when corporations were intended to serve a public purpose and if they failed to achieve that purpose within a reasonable time, they were expected to be held accountable for that failure.  

One of the primary problems of government before the 20th century was that it was difficult to tax economic activities and the fees corporations paid were one way to generate government revenues.  The original corporations were often given some monopoly power as a way to attract investors and then the corporation had to pay a share of the profits to the government.  Or in some cases, corporations were also used to advance other pubic policy goals such as beating foreign rivals in colonial power grabs or building canals because such ventures were too expensive and risky for the government to fund directly.

In all of the history of corporations until about 1856, shareholders were at least theoretically responsible if the company caused harm to the public although in practice, their actual risk of liability was very small. That officially changed in 1856 with the UK’s Limited Liability Act which limited liability for most corporations with more than 25 shareholders. In 1892, Germany copied the UK and expanded the scope of limited liability to include all corporations and even protected sole proprietors if they established a wholly-owned corporation.

In 1886, the US ruled that corporations are legal persons whose freedoms cannot be restricted under the 14th amendment. The 14th amendment had been written after the Civil War with the intention to protect the rights of emancipated slaves as persons, but ironically it was used to expand the personhood rights of corporations instead.  In the first 44 years after the 14th amendment was enacted, it was used to protect the rights of corporations in 312 cases and it was only used to decide about the rights of former slaves and their descendants in 28 cases.  

Kristen Alff argues that cultural acceptance of limited liability and corporate personhood took much longer than the legal rights and so even in Britain, the full acceptance of corporate personhood with limited liability did not happen until  World War I. 

With each legal innovation, business lobbying expanded the power of business by creating new species of corporations such as private equity companies which began in 1946, S-Corporations in 1958, special-purpose entity (SPE) a concept that was first coined in 1973, and Limited Liability Companies (LLCs) which Wyoming pioneered in 1977.  A LLC is not necessarily a corporation and most are sole-proprietorships or partnerships, but there are also some big private corporations like Crayola, Domino’s Pizza, and Ritz-Carlton have become LLCs.  The big advantage of an LLC is that it eliminates personal liability without requiring any corporate income taxes and there are fewer regulations on LLCs than on C-corporations or S-corporations. 

The success of businesses to lobby for more power can be seen in their recent success in achieving the right to spend unlimited money to lobby for more political power in the 2010 Citizen’s United case.  Before Citizen’s United, corporations had always been greatly restricted from using their might to influence elections and politicans and most financial  political process or at least  explicitly banned from .  Wealthy business people have always had lots of creative ways to get around those laws and use their money to buy influence, but it was legally constrained in well-run democracies.  Now that unlimited corporate money can flood into the American political process, the data shows a large increase in corporate political expenditures and that is just the money that we can track.  Citizen’s United also legalized unlimited dark money spending that intentionally  helps (often corporate) donors hide their identity to shield them from embarrassment.  

The original idea that corporations should serve some public interest was always part of the social fabric at least in theory.  Corporations often fell short of that ideal in practice, and that was one of the reasons why they were so unpopular going all the way back to Adam Smith and beyond.  But even the theory that they should serve the public good fell away in the 1970s and 80s with the rise of neoliberal ideology.  Notably, Milton Friedman published an essay in 1962 (republished in 1970 and several more times) in which he argued that, “The Social Responsibility of Business is to Increase its Profits.”  

That ideology was radical at first, but it began to spread in business schools and law schools and the idea that corporations should do nothing but extract profits for their elite owners has come to be the social norm which has even achieved some legal standing.  A CEO of an ordinary corporation can be sued by shareholders for doing anything that benefits society at a cost to profits.  It is rare, but it has happened beginning in at least 1919.  In response to this legal reality, the B Corporation was developed in 2010 in Maryland to give legal protection to management if they do something that benefits the public at the expense of shareholders.  

The powers, responsibilities, and structures of corporations have been changing for thousands of years up through recent changes for bad (such as Citizen’s United) and for good (such as the B Corporation).   Corporations are powerful and can be a force for good, but power is dangerous and as JK Galbraith claimed in his 1967 book, The New Industrial State, corporations have become so powerful that they have transcended competing sources of countervailing power such as democratic accountability.

Even though corporations are a growing fraction of the US economy, they comprised only 18% of US firms in 2010.  That may seem small, but they generated 82% of revenues which means that corporations are the core of the machinery of capitalism today.  This machinery is continually evolving as governments change the legal design of how corporations must be structured. 

The government is even more deeply involved in designing the structure of the corporations that are the most important part of capitalism: finance. 

The three biggest corporations of all time (by market capitalization) were colonial shipping companies: the Dutch East India Co., the Mississippi Co. and the South Sea Co.  After adjusting for inflation, they were more than double the size of today’s biggest company, Apple

Advertisement
Posted in Managerial Micro
3 comments on “A history of the Corporation
  1. […] companies was also impossible without mass literacy and easy written communication. In particular, the corporation was impossible because it was a form of mass democracy which relied upon cheap printed […]

  2. […] corporations authoritarian or democratic?  Corporations are hierarchical institutions in which workers often […]

  3. […] Corporate anthropomorphism wherein people act like a corporation (or other group) is a moral person that is separate from the individuals that run it. This is frequently used to shield decisionmakers from moral responsibility as illustrated by the concept of limited liability. […]

Leave a Comment

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out /  Change )

Twitter picture

You are commenting using your Twitter account. Log Out /  Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out /  Change )

Connecting to %s

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.

Enter your email address to follow this blog and receive notifications of new posts by email.

Join 92 other subscribers
Blog Archive